|
PEA-Amari
as Electoral Controversy
Robert Rivera, SJ, ICSI
Even as we have been collectively desensitized to controversy during
the campaign period, the Public Estates Authority-Amari imbroglio seems to represent a
scandal of truly epic proportions. If mudslinging has been the order of the day in the
electoral derby, then PEA-Amari would certainly be one of the largest and slimiest
mudballs of all. The political adversaries of the Ramos administration maintain that no
less than the president himself is culpable. The crime: selling out the government's
interests by favoring Amari Coastal Bay Resources and Filinvest Development--topping off a
growing list of other corporate beneficiaries--over higher bidders in various lucrative
real estate development schemes.
Ramos anointee Jose de Venecia is widely rumored to have been
influential in deciding the outcome of the PEA-Amari transactions as well, with various
presidential contenders claiming to "have the goods" on the former speaker.
President Ramos, in his spirited counterattack, has dismissed these accusations and
trained his guns on former PEA board member Arturo Trinidad, who has whipped up quite a
tempest with his disclosures about the president's preferential treatment of various
business interests.
With the results of the elections hanging in the balance, the PEA-Amari
scandal has temporarily receded from public view. A suit attempting to void the PEA-Amari
deal has been recently dismissed by the Supreme Court. Various presidential aspirants,
however, have already promised investigations into the role of the Ramos administration in
the scandal. Moreover, the controversy will certainly have repercussions on the economic
agenda of the next administration.
Whether the charges levelled against the Ramos administration are
indeed true or simply part of the electoral muckraking that is to be expected during the
campaign period, the PEA-Amari et al affair allows us to appreciate the
complexities involved in the privatization of government assets. The divestment of state
controlled property, enterprises, and services has long been the subject of intense
economic analysis and debate in many European and North American countries. In an
insightful volume entitled Bureaucrats in Business, the World Bank (WB) analyzes
the political considerations in the transfer of state operated enterprises (SOE's) to the
private sector. Many of the WB policy paper's recommendations certainly resonate with the
travails currently being encountered in the Philippine privatization process.
For instance, in the section entitled "The Politics of Reforming
SOE's," the WB suggests three important norms to help overcome the obstacles to SOE
reform and privatization. First, the reform undertaken must be politically desirable
to the leadership and its constituencies, with the political benefits outweighing the
political costs. Second, it must be politically feasible; leaders must have the
means to enact reforms and overcome the opposition by winning them over, or by compelling
them to comply. Finally, the whole conduct of the reform process must be credible.
The investors should be convinced that the government will not take over privatized
property once more, and any persons to be displaced by the reform or privatization (e.g.
government employees) should be properly compensated.
Unfortunately, the PEA affair has revealed how Philippine government
and the public in general has been amiss as far as these three norms are concerned. With
regard to the political desirability of the PEA privatization projects, opposition and
cause oriented groups can be faulted for not sufficiently looking and anticipating the
complex issues involved. Thus, misdeeds associated with the transfer from government to
private ownership fall into public scrutiny only when the projects are already well into
their implementation. Many pundits have already aired, with good reason, their doubts
about the suspicious timing of the Trinidad revelations.
The blame for the political unfeasibility of the PEA privatization
initiatives, on the other hand, falls squarely on the government. Because of a fundamental
lack of transparency in the way the bidding process and the selection of winners has been
conducted, the government now seems hard pressed to explain why the companies in question
received the contracts. The president, for one, has feebly explained that the deals
involved were "flagship projects," not categorically denying Trinidad's
allegations, and resorting instead to attacking the credibility of the government's
detractors.
Ensuring the political credibility of any privatization initiatives
will thus be dependent on both government and civil society representatives. The
government should ensure that the guidelines for proper divestment are followed, and that
any aggrieved parties are properly compensated. Various advocates should keep a watchful
eye on the conduct of the privatization process, so that they may not simply be "too
late the hero," but instead genuinely concerned with the proper implementation of the
privatization projects. Both government and civil society representatives should be
vigilant in ensuring that the property or enterprise to be privatized will truly be
utilized for the common good.
The WB report points out that the political acceptability of SOE reform
is usually high when governments are in transition; the transfer of Marcos controlled
assets to the private sector during the Aquino administration is an example (although the
Presidential Commission on Good Government was not itself totally free from scandal). The
Ramos government did not have this advantage,and neither will its successor. The next
administration should thus work hard, together with the private sector, to ensure that the
political desirability, feasibility, and credibility of privatization are achieved. If
not, the privatization initiaves of the next government could very well be stuck in the
mud of controversy. |